|
|||||
Introduction
to Economics ECO401
VU
Lesson
11.6
THE
FOUR BIG MACROECONOMIC
ISSUES AND THEIR
INTER-RELATIONSHIPS
(CONTINUED.......)
Link
between growth and the
various factors of
production:
Before
we move to neo-classical and
endogenous growth theories,
let us gain a better
understanding
of the link between growth
and the various factors of
production. We begin by
recalling
the familiar Cobb-Douglas
constant returns to scale
production function: Y
= KαL1-α for
a
hypothetical economy. Here Y
denotes output, K denotes
capital (machines, buildings
etc.),
L
denotes labour, and α
is a
parameter that lies between
0 and 1. Dividing both sides
by L and
substituting
Y/L = y (per capita output),
and K/L = k (per capita
capital), we have the per
capita
production
function y = kα.
Labor
and Capital:
Now
for a given L and no
depreciation, an increase in K should
translate into an increase in
k
and
through it an increase in y. This is an
example of capital deepening
induced growth.
However,
when there is depreciation
(say at a rate d% p.a.) of
the capital stock and
the labour
supply
is growing at n% p.a., capital
must grow at least by (d+n)%
p.a. in order keep K/L, or
k,
constant.
This is called capital
widening, i.e. more capital
being created but spread
over a
larger
population so as to deliver the
same K/L. The per
capita output impact of
capital
widening
is zero, because k remains
the same.
Now
taking capital as fixed,
let's analyze the ways in
which labour can serve as
the engine of
growth.
It is obvious that an increase in
the no. of labour hours
worked would expand
output.
However,
historically, the working
week has been shortened
from 6 to 5 days so it would
be
incorrect
to cite this as the major
source of world economic
growth over the last
century. What
else
could therefore have driven
the rapid expansion of
production in the 20th century. It might
be
the case that there
are now more people on
the labour force, due to
perhaps a larger
proportion
of women doing marketable
jobs (which is historically
accurate). Then it might
be
that
the quality of human capital
has gone up. The
same workers, because they
are better
educated
and have better skills,
can produce more output
using the same amount of
capital.
Japan
and Germany are prime
examples of this i.e. of
countries which achieved
very high
growth
rates despite having very
low levels of physical
capital left after World
War II. It was
the
quality
of these countries' human
capital which made the
difference.
Land:
Let's
now concentrate on land. The
earliest thinking on this
was all doom and
gloom. Malthus
(1798),
for instance, noted that
the supply of land, esp.
agricultural land, was
fixed, whereas
world
population was rising fast.
Given diminishing returns
(in terms of marginal food
product)
to
labour, the implication was
obvious: world hunger. While
the starvation hypothesis
did come
true
for come countries, it did
not happen for the
whole world. Why?
Predominantly because
of
unanticipated productivity
improvements in agricultural
production.
Technological
breakthroughs,
like tractors, fertilizers,
etc. increased yields per
acre by many 100s of
percents
permitting a food output
that far exceeded world
food requirements even with
a larger
population.
Today, land does not
feature centrally in growth
theory, as many countries
(e.g.
European
countries, Japan, Singapore,
Hong Kong, etc.) were
seen to achieve very
high
growth
rates while geographically
much larger South Asian,
Latin American and
African
countries
lagged behind.
Land
is one type of natural
resource that goes into
production. The other type
is raw materials
like
mineral wealth or timber.
The important point about
these resources is that some
of them
they
are not renewable (like
oil, coal, gas and
other minerals), while
others are: timer, fish
etc.
It
is important to take these
concerns into consideration
when talking about the
ability of a
particular
type of natural resource to
act as the engine of
growth.
The
above is not true for
technical progress, however,
which neither depletes nor
requires
renewing.
An essential and important
ingredient in the production
process, the
technical
121
Introduction
to Economics ECO401
VU
knowledge/stock
of a country is additive and
cumulative and depends on
the pace of
invention,
innovation
and learning by doing that
is happening in the economy. In
order to protect the
incentive
to invent and innovate,
governments introduce patent
and copyright laws which
grant
the
inventor monopoly production
rights for a certain period.
Also governments directly
or
indirectly
fund research and
development activities which
are the engine for
invention and
innovation.
Neo-classical
thinking on growth:
Neo-classical
thinking on growth is owed to
Robert
Solow whose
exogenous
growth
models
in
the mid-20th century remained the
most influential work in the
area till the late
1980s
when
endogenous growth theories
revolutionized thinking in this
area.
Based
on the principle of diminishing
returns to capital, the
main theses of the
neo-classical
exogenous
growth theory
were:
a.
The steady-state growth rate
of real GDP depends on n and
t, the exogenous rates
of
growth
of population and technology. By
exogenous, we mean determined
outside the
model.
Thus, there were no policy
insights for how governments
could affect the
steady
state
growth rates of countries. In
particular, the model
suggested that higher
savings
could
only have a level effect on
income, not a long-term
growth effect as had
been
earlier
thought. The reason was
that savings-enabled investment
and capital
accumulation
eventually banged into
diminishing returns.
b.
If one country started with
lower income and capital
than another country, then
the
poorer
country would grow faster in
order to catch up with the
richer country.
Eventually,
both would grow at the
same rate.
Major
Weaknesses of Exogenous Growth
Model:
Exogenous
growth theory suffered from
three major
weaknesses:
i.
It could not explain
why the gap between
the poor and rich
countries had widened
(anti-catch
up),
ii.
It could not explain why
some countries in East Asia
had apparently grown
consistently
on the back of higher saving
rates, and
iii.
It modeled technology as exogenous,
and beyond the influence of
policy.
The
first weakness was
answerable within the
neo-classical framework: the
key insight was
that
convergence would only be
witnessed among countries
with similar capital and
income
levels
to start with; countries
with very low capital to
start with might actually
never grow out of
their
poverty and could see
their capital stock falling
over time.
The
second weakness was
addressed by endogenous growth
theory (endogenous
because
the
steady state growth rate
was determined inside the
model, not determined by
factors
exogenous
to it) which set up the
model in a way that the
steady state growth rate
now
depended
directly on the saving rate
and level of technology. A
permanent increase in
the
saving
rate, therefore, meant a
permanent increase in the
growth rate.
The
third weakness was
also addressed by endogenous
growth theory, which by
using
different
industry structures and
technology functions specifications
could link
technological
progress
to conscious R&D effort by firms
and government. Non-diminishing
returns to
technical
progress would then generate
endogenous growth.
122
Table of Contents:
|
|||||