|
|||||
Introduction
to Economics ECO401
VU
Lesson
11.3
THE
FOUR BIG MACROECONOMIC
ISSUES AND THEIR
INTER-RELATIONSHIPS
(CONTINUED.......)
Causes
of Inflation:
There
are three views
here:
a.
The Traditional Keynesian
View.
b.
The cost push
inflation
c.
The monetarist view.
a.
The
traditional Keynesian view
which
sees inflation and
unemployment as opposite
sides
of the same coin, so is
merely a result of excessive
aggregate demand
(demand-
pull
inflation). Assuming that
increases in aggregate demand in a
Keynesian world do
have
some output and employment
impact, one can think of
plotting the
relationship
between
inflation and unemployment as
trade-off: a downward sloping
curve in
inflation-unemployment
space. This curve is called
the Phillips curve names
after the
economist
who first quantitatively
documented this trade-off in
the context of the UK
economy
in the 1950s and 60s.
The Phillips curve tradeoff
can be summarized as
follows:
Lower unemployment can be
achieved only at the cost of
higher inflation. The
policy
prescription flowing from
this particular diagnosis of
inflation was simple:
reduce
aggregate
demand by contractionary fiscal
and/or monetary
policies.
b.
Cost-push
inflation: This
view came to fore in the
1970s when the world
was
confronted
with a situation of rising
prices but high unemployment
(stagflation),
something
that demand-pull theories
could not explain. It was
observed that the two
oil
price
shocks in the 1970s, which
were essentially supply side
shocks (because they
increased
the cost of production),
were capable of producing
such a situation. In
AD-
AS
space, such a supply shock
would be shown by shifting
the AS curve to the
left
(and
up) causing prices to rise
and output (and employment)
to fall. In the context
of
the
Phillips curve, the supply
shock would be shown by
shifting the Phillips curve
out to
the
right, reflecting a structural
shift in the inflation-unemployment
trade-off. The name
given
to the resulting higher
inflation (at any level of
unemployment) was
cost-push
inflation.
The policy prescription
appropriate for dealing with
it, included
supply-side
measures
such as developing alternative
energy sources, fuel
efficient technologies,
production
cost reduction methods, and
reducing tax distortions
(that reduce the
incentive
to produce), increasing competition
(in search of productivity
gains), removing
price
floors etc. Keynesian demand
management policies were
obviously not seen as
relevant
in this context. It is important to
note that sometimes what
appears as cost-
push
inflation is actually driven by
higher demand. For e.g.,
let's say demand
for
property
increases in an economy; this
causes housing prices to
rise, causing rents
to
rise,
causing workers to demand
higher wages. Higher wages
cause firms'
production
costs
to increase prompting them to
raise goods prices which in
turn causes retail
prices
to rise. At every point of
the who chain, it is the
costs that are rising
(rental costs,
production
costs, purchase costs of
retailers), but the cause of
these rising costs is
higher
demand for property. This
situation is often branded
cost-push illusion.
c.
The
Monetarists View: Monetarists
located the causes of
inflation in the
Quantity
Theory
of Money (QTM), which
provided an explanation for
inflation totally
independent
from
that for unemployment. QTM
states: MV = PQ, where M is
the real money
supply,
V
is the velocity of money
(the no. of times money is
circulated in the economy in
a
year),
P is the price level and Q
is the real output. Assuming
a constant V and a
stable
(natural
rate) output Q*, changes in
P could be explained totally by
changes in M. A
stable
M would imply a stable P.
Thus the Monetarist key to
solving the inflation
problem
was a stable money supply
set to grow at the rate of
growth of natural
rate
output
(Q*). For Monetarists, the
concern was not the
government's expansionary
114
Introduction
to Economics ECO401
VU
fiscal
policy per se, but
the manner in which the
fiscal deficit was financed.
If the
government
financed its deficit by
borrowing from the central
bank (i.e. printing
money,
and
thus expanding money
supply), this would be
tantamount to inflationary finance
of
the
budget. If, however the
government financed the
deficit by borrowing from
banks or
the
retail savers, then there
would be little inflationary
consequences.
It
is also instructive to see
how Monetarist's viewed the
Phillips curve, and the
inflation-
unemployment
tradeoff. Monetarists believed
that the economy generally
gravitated around a
full-employment
or natural rate level, and
any positive output or
employment impact of
inflationary
demand policies would have
be limited. The duration and
extent of this
limited
impact
would depend on how much
money illusion private
agents suffered from.
Money
illusion
is when agents base their
decisions on their expectations
about inflation (set in
period
t-1),
so that when government
driven actual inflation
(increase in prices and
wages) in period t
exceeds
expected inflation, agents
view the increase as real
rather than nominal,
and
therefore
erroneously spend more than
they should. In setting
expectations for period
t+1,
however,
they learn from the
previous period, raising
their inflationary expectations
based on
the
outcome in period t. Only an
inflation rate higher than
this new expected rate
can convince
them
to spend more. The net
effect of learn and error
process is that inflation
rises very
steeply
in response to continued
demand-injections by government until
the effect on
spending
and
employment is virtually zero a
vertical Phillips curve.
This is how
Monetarists
characterized
the long-term tradeoff
between output and
inflation, i.e. that there
was no trade-
off
and that expansionary demand
policies (i.e. expansionary
monetary policy) translated
fully
into
higher inflation with no
impact on employment
whatsoever.
115
Table of Contents:
|
|||||