|
|||||
Introduction
to Economics ECO401
VU
Lesson
8.3
INTRODUCTION
TO MACROECONOMICS
(CONTINUED...........)
Keynes'
suggestions were taken on
board by government but in a
rather different context
than
he
might have anticipated, i.e.
in the context of war. The
Second World War broke
out in 1939
and
the higher defense
expenditures by European governments to
finance the War gave
the
necessary
boost to aggregate demand.
But while the economy
emerged from its
low-demand
recession,
it now faced supply-side
destruction due to
war.
Keynes
was not a socialist, just
someone who believed the
market could not be left
alone. He
was
the brain child of
institutions such as the IMF, WB
and GATT.
Keynes
Demand Management
Policies:
Keynes
exerted a phenomenal influence on
economic thinking and
policy-making in the
20th
century
and to date. In the 1950s
and 60s, Keynesian demand
management policies
were
practiced
by many governments when
demand went "off" due to
cyclical fluctuations of
the
economy.
In recessions, the government
increased spending and
encouraged the private
sector
to
do the same. In booms the
opposite was done to cool
the economy down.
The
major problem with Keynesian
demand management policies
was that they
viewed
unemployment
and inflation to be the
opposite sides of the same
coin. Thus, if
unemployment
was
high, prices must be low
and vice versa. Keynes'
policies could not be
applied in a situation
where
both prices and unemployment
were rising (stagflation)
this situation arose in the
1970s
with
the two oil price
shocks (which were
essentially supply side
shocks), and led to the
decline
of
Keynesian economics.
The
Monetarist School:
The
Monetarist School, led by
Milton Friedman separated
the explanation for
inflation and
unemployment.
He noted that inflation was
always and everywhere a
monetary phenomenon
and
the key to keeping inflation
low was to keep monetary
growth aligned with expected
real
output
growth.
The
Real Business Cycles (RBC)
School:
The
Real Business Cycles (RBC)
School also gained currency
in the 1970s. The exponents
of
the
business cycles view noted
that output fluctuated
mainly due to technology
shocks faced by
the
economy, and that no
Keynesian type policy could,
or should attempt to,
neutralize their
effects.
The
Rational Expectations
School:
The
same period, 1970s, saw
the rise of the rational
expectations school (as
opposed to
Keynes'
static expectations hypothesis)
led by such people as Robert
Lucas, Robert Barro
and
Thomas
Sargent who conceptualized
agents as making use of all
the information available
to
them,
and not just past
information, while making
decisions. Under these and
other conditions
they
showed that predictable
macroeconomic policies (like
Keynesian demand
management
policies)
had no effect on real output
or unemployment.
Neo
Classical Economics:
Coupled
with the insights of the
monetarist and business
cycle schools, this view of
the world
reinforced
the pre-Keynesian beliefs in
the power of the free
market and stressed the
micro-
foundations
of macroeconomics. For this
reason, it is called new or
Neo Classical
Economics.
The
Neo Keynesian
School:
Since
the 1980s, the new or
Neo Keynesian School has
emerged, led by economists
such as
Joseph
Stiglitz. The new Keynesians
have highlighted market
failures at the micro level
that may
arise
due to information asymmetries
and coordination failures
(moral hazard and
adverse
selection
problems). As such they have
shown avenues for meaningful
government intervention.
This
is broadly where modern
macroeconomics currently
stands.
83
Introduction
to Economics ECO401
VU
END
OF UNIT 8 EXERCISES
Which
of the following are
macroeconomic issues, which
are microeconomic ones
and
which
could be either depending on
the context?
a)
Inflation.
b)
Low wages in certain service
industries.
c)
The rate of exchange between
the pound and the
euro.
d)
Why the price of cabbages
fluctuates more than that of
cars.
e)
The rate of economic growth
this year compared with
last year.
f)
The decline of traditional
manufacturing industries.
a)
Macro. It refers to a general
rise in prices across the
whole economy.
b)
Micro. It refers to specific
industries
c)
Either. In a world context, it is a
micro issue, since it refers
to the price of one currency
in
terms
of one other. In a national
context it is more of a macro
issue, since it refers to
the
euro
exchange rate at which all
UK goods are traded
internationally. (This is certainly
a
less
clearcut division that in
(a) and (b)
above.)
d)
Micro. It refers to specific
products.
e)
Macro. It refers to the
general growth in output of
the economy as a
whole.
f)
Micro (macro in certain
contexts). It is micro because it
refers to specific industries.
It
could,
however, also help to
explain the macroeconomic
phenomena of high
unemployment
or balance of payments
problems.
This
question is about the merits
and demerits of an economic
system (like
socialism)
which
mainly focuses on ways of
achieving equality of incomes
and wealth across
citizens.
Would it ever be desirable to
have total equality in an
economy?
The
objective of total equality
may be regarded as desirable in
itself by many people. There
are
two
problems with this
objective, however.
The
first is in defining equality. If
there were total equality of
incomes then households
with
dependants
would have a lower income
per head than households
where everyone was
working.
In other words, equality of
incomes would not mean
equality in terms of standards
of
living.
If on the other hand,
equality were to be defined in
terms of standards of living,
then
should
the different needs of
different people be taken
into account? Should people
with special
health
or other needs have a higher
income? Also, if equality
were to be defined in terms
of
standards
of living, many people would
regard it as unfair that
people should receive
different
incomes
(according to the nature of
their household) for doing
the same amount of
work.
The
second major problem
concerns incentives. If all
jobs were to be paid the
same (or people
were
to be paid according to the
composition of their household),
irrespective of people's
efforts
or
skills, then what would be
the incentive to train or to
work harder?
Is
it possible to disagree with
the positions that the
different countries have
been
assigned
in the spectrum diagram in
Lecture 25 based on one's
general knowledge
about
these
countries' economic
systems?
Yes.
Given that there is no
clearly defined scale by
which government intervention is
measured,
the
precise position of the
countries along the spectrum
is open to question.
Which
macroeconomic problem(s) has/have
generally been less severe
since in the
early
1990s
than in the
1980s?
Inflation
and, since the mid-1990s,
unemployment. We must remember
that unemployment was
a
major problem in the 1920s
and 1930s (during the
Great Depression) and
inflation was a major
problem
in the 1970s and early
1980s.
This
question is about wages,
about whose rigidity and
flexibility Classical
economists
and
Keynes argued for long. Why
are real wages likely to be
more flexible
downwards
than
money (or nominal)
wages?
84
Introduction
to Economics ECO401
VU
Money
(or nominal) wages are
unlikely to fall. The reason
is that price inflation is
virtually always
positive.
Thus if money wages were to
fall, there would have to be
a bigger fall in real
wages.
For
example if inflation were 10
per cent and firms
wanted to cut money wages by
5 per cent,
this
would mean cutting real
wages by 15 per cent:
something they would find
hard to get away
with.
Real wages, on the other
hand frequently do fall.
Because wage agreements are
usually
made
in money terms, it only
needs inflation to go ahead of
money wage increases, and
real
wages
will fall.
Another
reason why money wages
are less flexible downwards
has to do with money
illusion.
People
will resist a cut in money
wages, seeing this as a
clear cut in their living
standard. If,
however,
a money wage increase is
given a bit below the
rate of inflation (i.e. a
real wage cut),
many
workers will perceive this
as an increase and will be
more inclined to accept it.
And
indeed,
because pay increases
normally occur annually, any
money rise (even if below
the
annual
rate of inflation) will be a
temporary real rise for a
few months, until inflation
overtakes it.
Would
it be possible for a short-run AS
curve to be horizontal at all
levels of output?
No.
Given that some factors
are fixed in supply in the
short run, there will
inevitably be a limit to
output.
As that limit is approached,
the AS curve will slope
upwards until it becomes
vertical at
that
limit.
If
firms believe the aggregate
supply curve to be relatively
elastic, what effect will
this
belief
have on the outcome of an
increase in aggregate
demand?
Firms
will respond to the increase
in aggregate demand by increasing
their output and
investment.
There are two main
reasons. The first is that
they will expect output
elsewhere to
increase
and that they will
therefore be able to obtain
supplies. The second is
that, if they
believe
that the rise in aggregate
demand is not going to cause
inflation to increase
significantly,
they
will not expect the
government to start deflating
the economy and thus
dampening demand
again.
They will therefore expect
their increased sales to
continue.
What
might be the negative
effects of higher government
expenditure (the
suggested
policy
prescription of Keynes) on the
private sector?
Increased
government expenditure (financed
from borrowing from banks)
has two possible
negative
effects on the private
sector: financial crowding
out and resource crowding
out. In the
former,
higher government borrowing
from banks leaves fewer
loanable funds with banks to
lend
to
the private sector. In any
case, the interest rate
rises due to a higher demand
for lonabale
funds.
This has a negative impact
on private sector investment. As
for resource crowding
out,
government
projects could divert key
workers and other resources
that are in short supply
away
from
the private sector. Since
labour and other resources
are not homogeneous and
not
perfectly
mobile, resource crowding
out can occur even
when the economy has
some slack in it,
i.e.
is operating at less than
full employment.
What,
in Keynes's view, would be
the impact of a higher money
supply on output,
given
that
there "is" slack in the
economy?
A
rise in money supply results
in an increase in aggregate demand: as
people hold more
money
and
their consumption demand
increases. Interest rates
also fall causing investment
demand to
rise.
All this will lead to a
rise in output with little
increase in the level of
prices. Thus the
nominal
increase
in money supply translates
fully into a real increase,
delivering a strong
output
response
in the process.
What
would be the Classical
economists' criticism of this
argument?
That
the increases in money
supply would simply lead to
higher prices in the private
sector, and
that
the government projects
(public works etc.) would
lead to "full" crowding out
- financial and
resource.
Given that the cause of
the problem, to Classical
economists, was market
rigidities,
the
solution was to free-up
markets: to encourage workers to
accept lower wages,
and
producers
to charge lower
prices.
85
Introduction
to Economics ECO401
VU
In
the extreme Keynesian model,
is there any point in supply-side
policies?
Yes.
Successful supply-side policies, by
increasing potential output,
will shift the upward
sloping
and
vertical portions of the AS
curve to the right. As a
result, expansionary
demand
management
policies could now increase
output to a higher level
than before.
In
the new (or neo)
Classical model, should
supply side policies be used
as a weapon
against
inflation?
It
is important o understand that
new classical economics is
strongly inspired by
monetarist
thinking.
Monetarists separated the
explanation for inflation
and unemployment. According
to
them,
the way to reduce
unemployment was to invoke
supply side measures which
serve to
reduce
the natural rate of
unemployment, whereas demand
side policies (which for
monetarists
means
monetary policy) policies
should be used to tackle
inflation. Therefore the
answer to the
above
question is "no".
If
we assume that if prices and
wages are flexible and
agents form
expectations
rationally,
then is the task of the
macroeconomic policymaker
trivial?
The
answer is no. This question
is about neo-Keynesianism. As you
know, the debate
between
Classicals
and Keynes was related to
the functioning of markets
and the flexibility of
prices and
wages
therein. Keynes said wages
were rigid, Classicals said
they shouldn't be. Then
there was
the
debate between Keynesian
economists and neo-Classical
economists over how
agents
formed
expectations about the
future. Keynes believed in
static expectations whereas
neo-
Classical
economists believed in rational
expectations. Now if we assume
that prices and
wages
are
perfectly flexible and
expectations are rationally
formed, then we are
essentially subscribing
to
the laissez faire,
pre-Keynesian Classical view of
things., in which there was
very little role
for
government
intervention. However, this is
where neo-Keynesians come
in. The new
Keynesians
have
highlighted market failures at
the micro level that
may arise due to information
asymmetries
and
coordination failures (moral
hazard and adverse selection
problems). As such they
have
shown
avenues for meaningful
government intervention.
How
might expansionary aggregate
demand policy positively
affect aggregate
supply?
If
the expansion in demand
comes about due to higher
investment, and if the same
leads to
technological
change (this usually happens
in the very long run),
then the long-run AS
curve
might
also shift to the right. In
this case, the expansionary
impact on output and income
effect
will
be magnified.
Does
the shape of the long-run AS
curve depend on how the
`long' run is
defined?
Yes.
If the long run is defined
so as to include the possibility of
technological change
resulting
from
investment, then the
long-run aggregate supply
curve can be deemed
relatively elastic
(flat).
Assume
that there is a fall in
aggregate demand (for
goods). Trace through the
short-run
and
long-run effect on
employment.
Prices
fall. This causes the
real wage to rise. At this
real wage rate there is a
deficiency of
demand
for labour. In the short
run there will be an
increase in unemployment. In the
long run
the
deficiency of demand will
drive down the money
wage rate until the
real wage rate
has
returned
to its earlier level.
If
AS and AD in an economy intersect at a
point a, and after a
rightward shift in AD and
a
leftward
shift in AS, the new
equilibrium obtains at a g which is
vertically above point
a,
does
this necessarily imply that
the long-run AS curve is
vertical?
It
would only be so if the
upward shifts in the
(short-run) AS curves had
been entirely due to
the
increased
aggregate demand feeding
through into higher prices.
If, however, AS had
shifted
upwards
partly as a result of cost-push
pressures independent of aggregate
demand, then point
g
could still be vertically
above point a (i.e. if the
long-run AS curve were
upward sloping and
86
Introduction
to Economics ECO401
VU
had
shifted upwards). With an
upward-sloping long-run AS curve, if
there had been no
such
cost-push
pressures, g would be to the
north east of a. Alternatively, if
cost-push pressures
had
been
great enough, point g could
be to the northwest of point
a.
Is
it possible for the AS curve
shift to the right over
time? If it did how would
this
influence
the effects of the rises in
aggregate demand?
Potential
GDP, Yp, and hence AS,
will shift to the right
over time as potential
growth takes place
(new
resources discovered and new
technologies invented). Also
the rise in aggregate
demand
and
in output may lead to
increased investment and
hence a bigger capital
stock: this too
will
shift
Yp and AS to the right. The
rightward shift of Yp and AS
will allow the rise in
aggregate
demand
to lead to a bigger increase in
actual output (Y) and a
smaller increase in the
price level.
Assume
that there are two
shocks. The first causes
aggregate supply to shift to
the left.
The
second, occurring several
months later, has the
opposite effect on aggregate
supply.
Show
that if both these effects
persist over a period of
time, but gradually fade
away, the
economy
will experience a recession
which will bottom out
and be followed in
smooth
succession
by a recovery.
A
fall (leftward shift) in
aggregate supply in the new
classical model will reduce
output and hence
cause
a recession. If the shock
pushing the AS curve to the
left persists for a period
of time,
then
the recession will deepen as
aggregate supply falls, but
less and less quickly as
the effect
fades
away. If the second shock
has a rightward pushing
effect on the AS curve,
then, as the
first
effect fades away, the
second effect will become
relatively stronger. Output
will begin to rise
again
and gather pace as the
first effect disappears.
Whether output will continue
falling initially
after
the appearance of the second
effect depends on the
relative size of the two
effects at that
particular
stage.
If
you are living in a
Keynesian world and there is
slack in the economy and
room for
expansionary
macroeconomic policies, would
you introduce these policies
in a slow and
steady
manner or haphazardly and
suddenly?
Demand
management would have be
carried out in a steady and
predictable way since
Keynes
assigned
a lot of importance to certainty
and stability and the
confidence they give to
firms
undertaking
investment.
If
constant criticism of governments in
the media makes people
highly cynical
and
skeptical
about the government's
ability to manage the
economy, what effect will
this
have
on the performance of the
economy?
The
economy will become less
manageable! It may become
less stable and as a
result
investment
and growth may be lower
and inflation higher. The
worse people believe the
long-
term
economic prospects are for
the country, the more
pessimistic they are likely
to become,
and
thus the worse is likely to
be the actual performance of
the economy.
This
question is about the
Monetarist challenge to Keynesian
economics. Since this is
a
difficult
question to answer, I would
advise you to revisit it at
the end of the course
and
during
the discussion on inflation,
and the monetary
sector.
How
would a monetarist answer
the Keynesian criticisms
given below?
1.
`The time lag with
monetary policy could be
very long.' Monetarists do
not claim that
monetary
policy can be used to fine
tune the economy. It is
simply important to
maintain
a
stable growth in the money
supply in line with
long-term growth in
output.
2.
`Monetary and fiscal policy
can work together.'
Monetarists would argue that
it is the
monetary
effects of fiscal policy
that cause aggregate demand
to change. Pure
fiscal
policy
will be ineffective, leading
merely to crowding
out.
3.
`The velocity of money is
not stable, thus making
the predictions of the
quantity theory of
money
i.e. that monetary
growth must necessarily lead
to inflation is unreliable.'
Monetarists
would accept that the
velocity of money circulation
fluctuates in the
short
87
Introduction
to Economics ECO401
VU
term,
but they will argue
that there is still a strong
correlation between monetary
growth
and
inflation over the longer
term.
4.
`Changes in aggregate demand
cause changes in money
supply and not vice
versa.'
Monetarists
would argue that if
governments respond to a rise in
aggregate demand by
allowing
money supply to increase,
then that is their choice to
expand money supply.
If
they
had chosen not to and
had pursued a policy of
higher interest rates, then
money
supply
would have thereby been
controlled and aggregate
demand would soon
have
fallen
back again.
Suppose
that, as part of the
national curriculum, everyone in
the country had to
study
economics
up to the age of 16. Suppose
also that the reporting of
economic news by
the
media
became more thorough (and
interesting!). What effects
would these
developments
have
on the government's ability to
manage the economy? How
would your answer
differ
if you were a Keynesian from
if you were a new
classicist?
People's
predictions would become
more accurate (at least
that's what teachers of
economics
would
probably hope!). Thus
the government would be less
able to fool people. In the
new
classical
world there would be less
shifting of the short-run AS
curve or the short-run
Phillips
curve.
The government would find it
even more useless to try to
reduce unemployment by
demand-side
policy. On the other hand a
tight monetary policy would
be more likely to
reduce
inflation
very rapidly.
In
the Keynesian world,
correctly executed demand
management policy would be
seen to be so.
This
would create a climate of
confidence which would help
to encourage stable growth
and
investment.
On the other hand, poorly
executed government policy
would again be seen to
be
so.
This could cause a crisis of
confidence, a fall in investment
and a rise in
unemployment
and/or
inflation.
88
Table of Contents:
|
|||||