|
|||||
Introduction
to Economics ECO401
VU
Lesson
7.2
SELECTED
ISSUES IN MICROECONOMICS
(CONTINUED...............)
Supply
and Demand Curve for
Labor:
The
labour supply curve may
bend backwards above a
certain wage rate as the
income effect
of
higher income dominates the
substitution effect of higher
wages.
The
wage rate is the marginal
cost of labour to the firm
and is directly proportional to
the hours
worked.
The
demand curve for labour
can be derived from the
intersection of the wage
rate lines
(horizontal
parallel lines) and the
marginal revenue product of
labour (a downward
sloping
concave
function) given by MRPL =
MPPL x MRi,
where subscript "L" stands
for labour and
subscript
"i" stands for the
good which the labourer
helps produce.
The
Value of Marginal Product of
Labor (VMPL):
The
value of marginal productivity of
labor can be represented by
the following
formula:
The
value of marginal product of
labour (VMPL)
= MPPL
x Pi.
It
is equal to MRPL when
P = MC (as in perfect competition),
but otherwise VMPL >
MRPL.
One
important difference between
labour and land, capital is
that the latter two
can be
purchased
but labour can only be
rented.
A
rent
is
a periodic payment as a reward
for hiring the factor of
production for that
period,
where
the purchase price of
capital is the "value" of
owning that capital for
its entire life.
The
Net Present Value (NPV)
and Discounting:
Decisions
about purchasing capital or
land are often made on
the basis of the net
present
value
(NPV) associated with the
decision. The NPV of an asset is
the discounted value of
the
net
returns that the asset
generates over a period of
time plus the discounted
value of its
disposal
value at the end of the
period minus the initial
purchase cost.
Discounting
is the process of converting a
stream of future incomes and
expenses into a
present
value. The discount rate is
the rate at which the
future incomes are
discounted.
THE
ECONOMICS OF INFORMATION
PRODUCTS
The
economics of information products or
(internet products) involves
studying how economic
principles
apply to the production,
distribution and consumption of
these products.
The
internet has reduced the
marginal
cost of distributing information
to
zero, as once a
product
is launched on the web, any
number of potential customers
can access/view it
without
any
additional cost to the
producer of the
information.
Since
the average cost of
information product is falling
over the entire range of
output the
market
structure most consistent
with such a product is
(natural) monopoly.
Experience
goods are
goods that people must
get a flavor of before they
can consider buying
them.
70
Introduction
to Economics ECO401
VU
END
OF UNIT 7 - EXERCISES
WELFARE
ECONOMICS AND EXTERNALITIES
If
monopoly power existed in an
industry, would production be
above or below
the
socially
efficient level (assuming no
externalities)? Which would be
greater, MSB or P?
A
firm with monopoly power
produces where MR = MC. But
this is below the socially
efficient
level
of output which obtains
where P = MC.
Assuming
no externalities, and perfect
competition show that social
efficiency is
achieved
in the factor markets,
where: MSBf =
MRPf = Pf =
MDUf = MSCf (where MRP is
the
marginal product of a factor,
MDU is the marginal
disutility of supplying it and f
is
any
factor).
The
MRPf is
the marginal benefit to the
employer from employing a
factor. Profits will
be
maximised
where MRP = Pf.
The MDUf
is the
marginal cost to the factor
supplier from
supplying
a factor. The factor
supplier's `surplus' will be
maximised where Pf =
MDUf. Under
perfect
competition, since MRPf =
Pf for each producer,
and Pf
= MDUf for each factor
supplier,
then,
since the market price
for the factor (Pf) is
the same for all
firms and factor
suppliers,
then
MRPf =
MDUf for all firms
and factor suppliers. In the
absence of externalities in the
factor
market,
MSBf =
MRPf, and MDUf
= MSCf.
Thus: MSBf
= MRPf =
Pf = MDUf
= MSCf ,
i.e. MSBf
=
MSCf
Note:
The concepts in this
question will not be tested
in the exam.
Trace
through the effects in both
factor and goods markets of
the following:
a)
An increase in the productivity of a
particular type of
labour.
b)
An increase in the supply of a
particular factor.
The
following charts illustrate
the effects:
(a)
1.
Labour demand
→
→
→
MRPl↑ (i.e.
MSBl↑)
employment
of labour↑
W↑
MRPl >
W
2.
Labour supply
W↑
→ W
>
MDUl (i.e.
W
>
MSCl) →
supply
of labour↑
→
MDUl↑
(movement
up along MDUl and
hence MSCl curve)
.
These
adjustments would continue
until MSBl = MSCl.
3.
Producer supply
→
→
→
→
MRPl↑
MC↓
production↑
P↓
P
>
MC
(i.e.
P
>
MSC)
4.
Consumer demand
P↓
→ MU
>
P
→ consumption↑ → MU↓
(movement
down along MU
and
hence
MSB
curve)
These
adjustments would continue
until MSB
=
MSC
(in
goods markets).
(b)
1.
Factor supply
Sf↑ (i.e.
MSCf↓)
→
Sf >
Df
→
Pf↓
2.
Factor demand
71
Introduction
to Economics ECO401
VU
Pf↓ → MRPf >
Pf → employment
of factor↑
(movement
down along MRPf
and
hence MSBf curve)
These
adjustments would continue
until MSBf = MSCf.
3.
Producer supply
→
→
→
→
Pf↓
MC↓
production↑
P↓
P
>
MC
(i.e.
P
>
MSC)
4.
Consumer demand
P↓
→ MU
>
P
→ consumption↑ → MU↓
(movement
down along MU
and
hence
MSB
curve)
These
adjustments would continue
until MSB
=
MSC
(in
goods markets).
Note:
The concepts in this
question will not be tested
in the exam.
If
MUX/MUY were
greater than PX/PY,
how would consumers behave?
What would bring
consumption
back to equilibrium where
MUX/MUY =
PX/PY?
Consumers
would buy relatively more of
X and relatively less of Y.
But as they did
this,
MUX/MUY
would
fall (because of diminishing
marginal utility) until MUX/MUY =
PX/PY.
Note:
The concepts in this
question will not be tested
in the exam.
If
MCX/MCY were greater than
PX/PY
how
would firms
behave?
What
would bring
production
back into equilibrium where
MCX/MCY = PX/PY?
Firms
would produce relatively
more of good Y and
relatively less of good X.
But as they did
this,
MCX/MCY would fall (because of
the law of diminishing
returns and hence
increasing
marginal
costs as production increases)
until MCX/MCY = PX/PY.
What
are marginal external
costs?
The
different between marginal
social cost and marginal
private costs is marginal
external cost.
In
other words, it is the
marginal cost of the
externality to society.
Is
it likely that the MSB
curve will be parallel to
the MU curve? Explain your
reasoning.
No.
It is likely that the
marginal external costs of
consumption will increase as
more is
consumed,
and thus the curves
will get further apart
(making the MSB curve
steeper than the
MU
= MB curve). For example,
the marginal pollution costs
of cars gets progressively
greater as
more
and more cars come
onto the roads and
the environment becomes less
and less able to
absorb
the additional quantities of
pollutants.
Give
other examples of each of
the four types of
externality.
a)
External costs of production
(MSC > MC): The pollution
of rivers and streams by
slurry
and
nitrate run-off from farms;
road congestion near a
factory.
b)
External benefits of production
(MSC < MC): Beneficial
spin-offs from the
development of
new
products (for example, the
various space programmes in
the USA, the USSR
and
Europe
have contributed to advances in
medicine, materials technology,
etc.); where the
opening
of a new environmentally friendly
factory results in less
output from factories
that
pollute.
72
Introduction
to Economics ECO401
VU
c)
External costs of consumption
(MSB < MB): The effect of
CFC aerosols on the
ozone
layer;
the unpleasant sight of
kites stuck in trees and
wires.
d)
External benefits of consumption
(MSB > MB): People
decorating the outside of
their
houses
or making their gardens look
attractive benefits neighbours
and passers-by; car
owners
getting their cars properly
serviced so as to reduce the
smoke emitted and
the
pollution
associated with it.
Some
roads could be regarded as a
public good, but some
could be provided by
the
market.
Which types of road could be
provided by the market? Why?
Would it be a
good
idea?
Roads
where there are relatively
few access points and
where therefore it would be
practical to
charge
tolls. Charges could be
regarded as a useful means of
restricting use of the roads
in
question,
or, by charging more at peak
times, of encouraging people to
travel at off-peak
times.
Such
as system, however, could be
regarded as unfair by those
using the toll roads,
and might
merely
divert congestion onto the
non-toll roads.
Which
of the following have the
property of non-rivalry: (a) a
can of drink; (b)
public
transport;
(c) a commercial radio
broadcast; (d) the sight of
flowers in a public
park?
(a)
No. (b) No (passengers take
up seats). (c) Yes. (d)
Yes (unless I get in your
way!).
Give
some other examples of
public goods. Does the
provider of these goods
(the
government
or local authority) charge
for their use? If so is the
method of charging
based
on
the amount of the good
that people use? Is it a
good method of charging?
Could you
suggest
a better method?
Two
examples are: national
defence; urban roads. In
both cases the user is
not directly
charged.
The funding comes from
taxation. In the case of
roads, part of the funding
comes from
road
users generally (in the
form of taxes on petrol and
road fund licences) and
part from
general
or local taxation. Only in
the case of petrol tax is
the charging related to the
amount that
people
use the public good. It
encourages people to use the
roads less, and thus
takes into
account
the marginal cost (i.e.
repairs and maintenance) of
road provision. In this
sense,
however,
roads are not a pure
public good because using
them does create a small
amount of
wear
and tear on them (although a
significant portion of road
maintenance costs are due
simply
to
deterioration through
time).
If
the marginal cost of
provision is zero (as is the
case with a pure public
good) then charging
people
according to how much they
use it will not cause an
efficient allocation of resources:
with
a
zero marginal cost, the
price should be zero.
Charging people according to
how much they
use
it, however, could be
regarded as fair according to
the benefit principle
but not according
to
the principle of vertical
equity.
Name
some goods or services
provided by the government or
local authorities that
are
not
public goods.
Education,
health, libraries, parks.
Only limited people can
use these facilities.
If
health care is provided
free, the demand is likely
to be high. How is this high
demand
dealt
with? Is this a good way of
dealing with it?
It
is dealt with by a system of
queuing. Emergency cases are
usually dealt with
immediately, or
at
least very quickly, but
non-emergency cases may have
to wait weeks, months or
even years
for
treatment.
Many
people would argue that
for reasons of equity, and
the special nature of
health, it is better
to
solve the problem of waiting
lists by diverting more
resources into health care,
rather than by
using
a system of charging people.
Except where there are
initially idle resources
or
73
Introduction
to Economics ECO401
VU
inefficiencies,
this approach will result in
a lower provision of other
publicly provided goods
or
services,
or higher taxes.
How
would you attempt to value
time that you yourself
save (a) getting to work;
(b) going
on
holiday; (c) going out in
the evening?
The
approach is to ask what the
opportunity cost to you of
that time is. What
else could you
have
done with the time
and what, as a result, would
you have been prepared to
pay to save
time?
Thus in the case of (b), if
you have a long holiday
and the travel is seen as an
enjoyable
part
of it, then there may be no
time cost to you, or it may
even be seen as a benefit;
whereas if
you
only have a week off
work and want to get to
the sun as quickly as
possible, then you
will
want
to minimise travel time and
thus may be prepared to pay
quite a lot more to fly
rather than
go
over land.
Imagine
that a public project yields
a return of 13 per cent
(after taking into account
all
social
costs and benefits), whereas
a 15 per cent private return
could typically be
earned
in
the private sector. How
would you justify diverting
resources from the private
sector
to
this project?
If
it could be argued that this
particular project yielded
longer-term benefits, and
that the market
rate
of discount is too high in
the sense that it gives
undue weight to present
benefits and costs
over
future benefits and costs
than is socially desirable,
then there would be some
justification.
The
justification for a lower
social rate of discount is
that the market only
reflects the wishes
of
the
current generation, whereas
governments ought to take a
longer-term perspective.
An
alternative justification may be in
terms of the distribution of
costs and benefits. If the
project
was
an effective means of targeting
help to the poor (say a
new hospital in an area
where there
is
a lot of poverty) then the
government may want to apply
a lower rate of
discount.
Assume
that a project has an
initial construction cost of
Rs10 000, takes a year to
come
into
operation and then has a
life of 3 years. Assume that
it yields Rs5000 per year
in
each
of these 3 years. Is the NPV
positive at (a) a 10 per
cent discount rate; (b) a 15
per
cent
discount rate?
(a)
NPV = Rs.10 000 + Rs.5000/1.1 +
Rs.5000/1.21 + Rs.5000/1.331
=
Rs.10 000 + Rs.4545 +
Rs.4132 + Rs.3757
=
+Rs.2434
The
NPV is therefore positive at a 10 per
cent discount rate.
(b)
NPV = Rs.10 000 + Rs.5000/1.15 +
Rs.5000/1.3225 + Rs.5000/1.5209
=
Rs.10 000 + Rs.4348 +
Rs.3781 + Rs.3288
=
+Rs.1417
The
NPV is therefore still positive at a 15
per cent discount
rate.
Why
is this type of costbenefit
analysis (CBA) simpler to
conduct that ones
assessing
the
desirability of a new road or
airport?
There
are specific scenarios, with
very precise assumptions.
The main purpose was
not to
demonstrate
the positive NPV (which
depends on the assumptions
about the value of
the
environmental
benefits of reducing emissions),
but to compare the relative
advantages of the
alternative
scenarios.
With
a CBA of a new road or
airport, there have to be
assumptions, not only about
the
environmental
impact, but about the
value of time saved or
additional time incurred
by
travellers,
about the value of lives
saved or lost and about
the costs to local people
disturbed
by
the road or airport. Thus
the measurement of externalities is
likely to be more
problematic
than
in the case of lowering the
sulphur content of road
fuel.
How
do merit goods differ from
public goods?
They
could be provided by the
market (albeit with too
little consumed). The
problem of non-
excludability
does not apply.
Note:
The concepts in this
question will not be tested
in the exam.
74
Introduction
to Economics ECO401
VU
Summarize
the economic policies of the
major political parties. (If
it is near an election
you
could refer to their
manifestos.) How far can an
economist go in assessing
these
policies?
You
will need to look at the
current policies.
Economists
in their role as economists
cannot challenge fundamental
normative issues
such
as
whether it is desirable to have a
much more substantial
redistribution of income from
the
rich
to the poor. They can,
however, examine whether the
factual claims of the
parties are
correct,
and whether the policies
they advocate will bring
the effects they
claim.
Note:
The concepts in this
question will not be tested
in the exam.
Give
some examples of how
correcting problems in one
part of the economy will
create
problems
elsewhere.
Two
examples are:
·
A
local authority reduces
street parking in the centre
of a town in order to
reduce
congestion
on the streets, but succeeds
in encouraging commuters and
shoppers to
park
outside the town centre in
residential areas, thus
reducing the quality of life
for
those
living in those
areas.
·
The
government taxes the
consumption of electricity in order to
encourage people to
become
more fuel efficient and
thus to reduce power station
emissions. Some
people
respond
by switching to burning coal,
with the result that
emissions from this
source
increase.
THE
MARKET FOR FACTORS OF
PRODUCTION
Why
might the labour supply
curve be backward
bending?
Because
after a point the income
effect of the higher wage
dominates the substitution
effect.
Note
that when we talk of
substitution, it is substitution between
work and leisure. The
labourer
must
decide how to utilize his
time, i.e. how much
hours to spend working and
how much to
spend
relaxing. If the wage rate
(which also represents the
worker's income) becomes
very high,
given
that leisure is a normal
good, the demand for
relaxation increases. This is
the income
effect
and it is positive for
leisure and negative for
hours worked. However, as
the wage rate
increases,
the opportunity cost of
relaxing increases and
prompts the worker to work
more. This
is
the substitution effect and
is negative for leisure and
positive for hours worked.
The labour
supply
curve becomes backward
bending when the income
effect of higher wages
dominates
the
substitution effect.
What
is the distinction between
MRPL and
VMPL? When is this
distinction important?
Labour's
marginal revenue product
(MRPL)
= MR * MPPL
Labour's
value of marginal product
(VMPL)
= P * MPPL
The
two terms mean the
same when the product
market is perfectly competitive,
because then:
MR
= MC = P. However, when the
product market is not
perfectly competitive, for
e.g., if it is a
monopoly,
then P > MR at the profit
maximizing output, and
therefore VMPL >
MRPL. The
important
implication of this is that a
monopolist would pay
labourers less than the
"value of the
output
that their labour helps
produce", i.e. the VMPL. To
that effect this can be
viewed as
exploitation
of labour.
Do
any of the following
contradict marginal productivity
theory:
a)
Nationally negotiated wage
rates;
b)
Discrimination;
Even
if marginal productivity theory
were not relevant in these
cases, the theory would
still be
accurate
in the sense that if firms
wanted to maximise profits
then they should employ
workers
to
the point where MCL =
MRPL.
But
do any of the above four
cases necessarily contradict
marginal productivity
theory?
75
Introduction
to Economics ECO401
VU
a)
No, not necessarily. Firms
may find it convenient (in
terms of the costs of
negotiating
and
the avoidance of disputes) to
pay nationally agreed wage
rates. They then
could
employ
workers up to the point
where their MRP was equal to
this wage rate
(which,
given
that the firm was a
`wage taker' would be equal
to the MCL).
b)
Yes. Discrimination would
lead to firms employing
those workers against whom
they
were
discriminating below the
level where their MRP was
equal to their MCL.
Which
of the following are stocks
and which are
flows?
a)
Unemployment.
b)
Redundancies (job
lay-offs).
c)
Profits.
d)
A firm's stock market
valuation (share
price).
e)
The value of property after
a period of inflation.
Stocks:
(a), (d) and (e).
They are measurements at a
point in time.
Flows:
(b) and (c). They
are measurements over a
period of time. (Note that
(e) would only be
a
flow if it were measuring
the rise in the value of
property over a period of
time.)
What
is the present value of a
machine that lasts three
years, earns Rs.100m in year
1,
Rs.200m
in year 2 and Rs.200m in
year 3, and then has a
scrap value of
Rs.100m?
Assume
that the rate of discount is
5 per cent. If the machine
costs Rs.500m, is
the
investment
worthwhile? Would it be worthwhile if
the rate of discount were 10
per cent?
Using
the formula given in the
lectures:
PV
= Rs.100/1.05 + Rs.200/(1.05)² +
Rs.300/(1.05)³
=
Rs.95.24 + Rs.181.41 +
Rs.259.15
=
Rs.535.80
Thus
the investment is profitable at a
discount rate of 5 per cent
given that the machine
costs
Rs.500.
If
the rate of discount is 10
per cent, then the
present value this time is
given by:
PV
= Rs.100/1.1 + Rs.200/(1.1)² +
Rs.300/(1.1)³
=
Rs.90.91 + Rs.165.29 +
Rs.225.40
=
Rs.481.59
With
a 10 per cent discount rate,
therefore, the investment
would not be
profitable.
What
market price would a piece
of land sell for if it
earned Rs.10,000 rent per
year, and if
the
rate of interest were 5 per
cent?
According
to the formula, market price
of land = [annual rental
value (in Rs.) / interest
rate (in %
p.a.)]
Rs.10,000/0.05
= Rs.200,000.
What
does this tell us about
the relationship between the
price of an asset (like
land) and
the
rate of interest?
The
higher the rate of interest,
the lower the market
price of the asset. The
asset would have to
be
cheaper (i.e. yield a higher
rate of return) to persuade
the purchaser to sacrifice
the
alternative
of earning the market rate
of interest.
INFORMATION
ECONOMICS
There
are many dimensions to
information economics. The
first of these was touched
upon in
the
lectures on background on demand
under "demand under
uncertainty." We touched
76
Introduction
to Economics ECO401
VU
concepts
like moral hazard and
adverse selection. Below we
touch upon some of the
remaining
aspects
that were not covered
there. PART A contains
questions related to the
economics of
information
products on the web that
were covered in the lecture,
while PART B contains
other
"general"
information economics
issues.
PART
A:
What
has the internet done to
the cost of distributing
information?
It
has virtually brought down
this cost to zero.
Distributors can place
information on their
websites
and consumers can access it
or download it from there
without any additional cost
to
the
distributor. There are
however still the initial
costs of preparing the
information in a format
that
can be placed on the web,
and also the costs of
maintaining the website and
marketing the
website
to interested consumers of that
information. However, in terms of
the marginal cost of
distributing
information to one more
consumer, that cost has
now been brought down to
virtually
zero
by the internet.
What
are experience
goods?
These
are goods whose value
can be ascertained by the
consumer only after
experiencing or
consuming
it. For example if a
university wanted to deliver an
online course in say,
finance, it
might
allow potential students to
take part of the course
free and then if they
are satisfied they
could
proceed with a charge for
the remaining or whole of
the course. The same
principle
applies
to buying software on the
web. You are often given a
free trial version before
you asked
to
commit to buy the
software.
How
is it possible for companies
like MSN or yahoo to provide
free e-mail or
chatting
facilities
or "web space" to internet
users the world
over?
Everything
has a cost. Providing free
web space or e-mail account
to millions of users also
must
have
a cost. Now if the users
are not paying this
cost, someone else should.
This someone else
is
the ever-growing pool of
businesses (travel companies,
financial advisors,
supermarkets,
fashion
outlets you name it)
who wish to advertise their
products to millions of
potential
customers
worldwide. Yahoo and MSN,
because they have such a
large captive clientele
can
serve
as the ideal vehicle media
for their advertisements.
Thus you will see
that whenever you
log
on to the yahoo page there
is some advert that appears
without you asking. This is
to ensure
that
"all" users do actually see
the advert, so that "some of
them" buy the product
being
advertised.
PART
B
(YOU
WILL NOT BE TESTED ON THIS
IN THE EXAM)
Assume
that you wanted the
following information. In which
cases could you (i)
buy
perfect
information, (ii) buy
imperfect information, (iii) be
able to obtain
information
without
paying for it, (iv)
not be able to obtain
information?
a)
Which washing machine is the
most reliable?
b)
Which of two jobs that
are vacant is the most
satisfying?
c)
Which builder will repair my
roof most
cheaply?
d)
Which builder will make
the best job of repairing my
roof?
e)
Which builder is best value
for money?
f)
How big a mortgage
would it be wise for me to
take out?
g)
What course of higher
education should I
follow?
h)
What brand of washing powder
washes whiter?
In
which cases are there
non-monetary costs to you of
finding out the information?
How
can
you know whether the
information you acquire is
accurate or not?
77
Introduction
to Economics ECO401
VU
(a)
(i) or (ii);
(b)
(iii) (by asking
people currently doing the
job) or (iv);
(c)
(iii) (by obtaining
estimates);
(d)
(iii) (albeit imperfect, by
inspecting other work that
the different builders have
done) or (iv);
(e)
As (d);
(f)
(iii);
(g)
(iii);
(h)
(i) or (ii) (as in
(a)) or (iii) by
experimenting.
All
could involve the
non-monetary costs of the
time involved in finding
out.
If
th
If
the
information is purely factual
(as in (c) above), and
you can trust the
source of your
information,
there is no problem. If you
cannot trust the source, or
if the information is
subjective
(such
as other people's experiences in
(b) above), then you
will only have imperfect
information
of
the costs and/or benefits
until you actually
experience them.
Make
a list of pieces of information a
firm might want to know,
and consider whether
it
could
buy the information and
how reliable that
information might
be.
·
Some
examples include:
The
position and elasticity of
the demand curve: Market
research can provide some
information,
but
it is very unreliable, especially in an
oligopolistic environment, where
the actions of rival
are
unpredictable.
·
Next
year's wages bill:
The
information cannot be purchased,
but it could use its
own past experiences to
predict (albeit
imperfectly)
the outcome of wage
negotiations.
·
The
costs of alternative
inputs:
This
information is probably available
free from suppliers.
·
Ways of
saving taxes:
Employing
accountants can help the
firm save money
here.
What
type of information can be a
public good? (Clue: do not
confuse a public good
with
something
merely provided by the
government, which could also
be provided by the
private
sector.)
An
example of information that is
nearer to being a public
good, is information that is
simple
enough
not to require being
presented as a set of tables or as a
report. It can be told from
one
person
to another: as such it would be
difficult to enforce copyright. An
example would be the
current
rate of inflation or the
size of the balance of trade
deficit or surplus.
78
Table of Contents:
|
|||||