|
|||||
Investment
Analysis & Portfolio Management
(FIN630)
VU
Lesson
# 24
MARKET
EFFICIENCY Contd...
Behavioral
Finance:
Behavioral
finance is the study of the
influence of psychology on the
behavior of financial
practitioners
and the subsequent effect on markets.
Sewell says "I think of
behavioral
finance
as simply "open-minded finance".
Thaler says 'This area of
enquiry is sometimes
referred
to as "behavioral finance," but we
call it "behavioral economics."
Behavioral
economics
combines the twin
disciplines of psychology and economics
to explain why and
how
people make seemingly irrational or
illogical decisions when they
spend, invest, save,
and
borrow money."
This
paper examines the case
for major changes in the
behavioral assumptions underlying
economic
models, based on apparent anomalies in
financial economics. Arguments
for such
changes
based on claims of "excess volatility" in
stock prices appear flawed
for two main
reasons:
there are serious questions
whether the phenomenon
exists in the first place
and,
even
if it did exist, whether
radical change in behavioral assumptions is
the best avenue
for
current
research. The paper also examines
other apparent anomalies and suggests
conditions
under
which such behavioral
changes are more or less
likely to be adopted. Because
psychology
systematically explores human
judgment, behavior, and well-being, it
can teach
us
important facts about how
humans differ from
traditional economic assumptions. In
this
essay
I discuss a selection of psychological
findings relevant to economics.
Standard
economics
assumes that each person has
stable, well-defined preferences, and that
she
rationally
maximizes those preferences. Section 2 considers
what psychological
research
teaches
us about the true form of
preferences, allowing us to make economics
more realistic
within
the rational choice
framework. Section 3 reviews
research on biases in
judgment
under
uncertainty; because those biases lead
people to make systematic errors in
their
attempts
to maximize their preferences, this
research poses a more
radical challenge to
the
economics
model. The array of
psychological findings reviewed in
Section 4 points to an
even
more radical critique of the
economics model: Even if we
are willing to modify
our
familiar
assumptions about preferences, or allow
that people make systematic errors in
their
attempts
to maximize those preferences, it is sometimes
misleading to conceptualize people
as
attempting to maximize well-defined,
coherent, or stable preferences.
Market
efficiency survives the
challenge from the
literature on long-term return
anomalies.
Consistent
with the market efficiency
hypothesis that the
anomalies are chance
results,
apparent
overreaction to information is about as
common as under reaction and
post-event
continuation
of pre-event abnormal returns is
about as frequent as post-event
reversal. Most
important,
consistent with the market
efficiency prediction that apparent
anomalies can be
due to
methodology, most long-term
return anomalies tend to disappear
with reasonable
changes
in technique.
The
field of modern financial
economics assumes that people behave
with extreme
rationality,
but they do not.
Furthermore, people's deviations
from rationality are
often
systematic.
Behavioral finance relaxes
the traditional assumptions of financial
economics by
incorporating
these observable, systematic, and
very human departures from
rationality into
standard
models of financial markets. We
highlight two common mistakes
investors make:
excessive
trading and the tendency to
disproportionately hold on to losing
investments
while
selling winners. We argue that
these systematic biases have
their origins in
human
156
Investment
Analysis & Portfolio Management
(FIN630)
VU
psychology.
The tendency for human
beings to be overconfident causes the
first bias in
investors,
and the human desire to
avoid regret prompts the
second.
Behavioral
finance is a rapidly growing
area that deals with
the influence of psychology
on
the
behavior of financial practitioners.
Behavioral finance is the
application of psychology
to
financial behavior--the behavior of
practitioners. Behavioral finance is
the study of how
psychology
affects financial decision
making and financial markets.
Behavioral finance
argues
that some financial
phenomena can plausibly be understood
using models in which
some
agents are not fully
rational. The field has
two building blocks: limits
to arbitrage,
which
argues that it can be difficult
for rational traders to undo
the dislocations caused
by
less
rational traders; and psychology,
which catalogues the kinds of
deviations from full
rationality
we might expect to see. We
discuss these two topics,
and then present a number
of
behavioral finance applications: to
the aggregate stock market,
to the cross-section of
average
returns, to individual trading
behavior, and to corporate finance. We
close by
assessing
progress in the field and
speculating about its future
course.
Behavioral
finance and behavioral economics
are closely related fields
which apply
scientific
research on human and social
cognitive and emotional biases to
better understand
economic
decisions and how they affect
market prices, returns and the
allocation of
resources.
Risk
aversion:
Risk
aversion is a concept in economics,
finance, and psychology related to
the behavior of
consumers
and investors under uncertainty.
Risk aversion is the
reluctance of a person to
accept
a bargain with an uncertain
payoff rather than another
bargain with more certain,
but
possibly
lower, expected payoff.
Example:
A person is
given the choice between
two scenarios, one certain and one not.
In the
uncertain
scenario, the person is to make a gamble
with an equal probability
between
receiving
$100 or nothing. The alternative scenario
is to receive a specific dollar
amount
with
certainty.
Investors
have different risk
attitudes. A person is;
·
Risk-averse
if he or she would accept a
certain payoff of less than
$50 (for example,
$40)
rather than the
gamble.
·
Risk
neutral if he or she is in different
between the bet and a certain $50
payment.
·
Risk-seeking
(or risk-loving) if the
certain payment must be more
than $50 (for
example,
$60) to induce him or her to
take the certain option over
the gamble.
The
average payoff of the
gamble, known as its expected
value, is $50. The dollar
amount
accepted
instead of the bet is called the
certainty equivalent, and the
difference between it
and
the expected value is called
the risk premium.
157
Table of Contents:
|
|||||